基于全要素生產(chǎn)率的中國最優(yōu)城市規(guī)模研究
[Abstract]:The expansion of urban scale has both the side of aggregate economy and the side of uneconomic aggregation. Therefore, theoretically speaking, there should be an optimal urban scale or an appropriate interval for urban scale. In this range, the marginal income of aggregation and the marginal cost of aggregation are offset each other, and the net income of aggregation is maximized. House prices are an intuitive indicator of economic agglomeration and the forces leading to population dispersion. In China, house purchase expenditure accounts for a large part of household expenditure, while the statistics bureau does not calculate house prices in the process of CPI statistics. Therefore, this paper argues that CPI is not a good indicator of the difference of living cost between regions. For this reason, this paper establishes a CPI weighted cost-of-living index, (COL), to compare the COL adjusted per capita GDP, of each city, which is called "real per capita GDP". The results show that Beijing, Shanghai, Guangzhou, Although Shenzhen and other cities rank high in nominal per capita GDP, real per capita GDP ranks well above the top 25 because of the high cost of living. Based on the urban model established by Henderson and the panel data of cities at or above the prefectural level in China from 2005 to 2013, the total factor productivity (TFP) of each city is measured by using GDP adjusted by the cost of living index. The relationship between urban total factor productivity (TFP) and urban scale is studied. It is found that there is an inverted U-type relationship between urban scale and TFP. At the same time, it is also found that the interaction between urban scale and urban industrial structure has a positive effect on total factor productivity. The higher the industrial structure, the more obvious the increase of production efficiency brought by urban scale expansion. This paper also calculates the optimal city size under the current industrial structure level and the upper and lower limits of the appropriate city size at 95% confidence level. In order to compare with the existing literature, this paper also constructs a model to study the relationship between urban scale and urban labor productivity. Although this paper also obtains the inverted U-shaped relationship between urban scale and urban labor productivity, and the optimal urban scale is not different from the existing literature. However, it is found that the optimal city size obtained by using total factor productivity as the explanatory variable is smaller than that obtained by labor productivity. This shows that the optimal city size of maximizing total factor productivity is smaller than that of labor productivity maximization.
【學(xué)位授予單位】:華中科技大學(xué)
【學(xué)位級別】:碩士
【學(xué)位授予年份】:2016
【分類號】:F299.2
【參考文獻】
相關(guān)期刊論文 前10條
1 陸銘;;戶籍制度需在特大城市突破[J];上海國資;2015年10期
2 梁婧;張慶華;龔六堂;;城市規(guī)模與勞動生產(chǎn)率:中國城市規(guī)模是否過小?——基于中國城市數(shù)據(jù)的研究[J];經(jīng)濟學(xué)(季刊);2015年03期
3 陳釗;陸銘;;首位城市該多大?——國家規(guī)模、全球化和城市化的影響[J];學(xué)術(shù)月刊;2014年05期
4 柯善咨;趙曜;;產(chǎn)業(yè)結(jié)構(gòu)、城市規(guī)模與中國城市生產(chǎn)率[J];經(jīng)濟研究;2014年04期
5 范紅忠;張婷;李名良;;城市規(guī)模、房價與居民收入差距[J];當(dāng)代財經(jīng);2013年12期
6 陸銘;;重思“城市病”[J];中國經(jīng)濟報告;2013年02期
7 陳利鋒;范紅忠;李伊涵;;生產(chǎn)與人口的集中促進了經(jīng)濟增長嗎?——來自日本的經(jīng)驗和教訓(xùn)[J];人口與經(jīng)濟;2012年06期
8 陸銘;高虹;佐藤宏;;城市規(guī)模與包容性就業(yè)[J];中國社會科學(xué);2012年10期
9 袁正;鄭勇;韓驍;;城市規(guī)模與居民幸福感的關(guān)系[J];城市問題;2012年05期
10 王小魯;;中國城市化路徑與城市規(guī)模的經(jīng)濟學(xué)分析[J];經(jīng)濟研究;2010年10期
相關(guān)博士學(xué)位論文 前3條
1 周陽;基于生活成本調(diào)整的真實產(chǎn)出和中國地級以上城市的適宜規(guī)模研究[D];華中科技大學(xué);2012年
2 何志揚;城市化道路國際比較研究[D];武漢大學(xué);2009年
3 楊振;中國人口與經(jīng)濟空間分布關(guān)系研究[D];蘭州大學(xué);2008年
,本文編號:2423904
本文鏈接:http://www.sikaile.net/jingjilunwen/jiliangjingjilunwen/2423904.html